Question A:
Unless they have inside information, very few investors, if any, can consistently make accurate predictions about whether the price of an individual stock will rise or fall on a given day.
Responses
Responses weighted by each expert's confidence
Question B:
Plausible expectations of future dividends, discounted using a plausible risk-adjusted interest rate, explain well the level of stock prices for recently listed internet businesses in 1999.
Responses
Responses weighted by each expert's confidence
Question A Participant Responses
Participant | University | Vote | Confidence | Bio/Vote History |
---|---|---|---|---|
Daron Acemoglu |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Joseph Altonji |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Alan Auerbach |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
David Autor |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
Experts are generally no better than the rest of us -- often worse.
|
||||
Katherine Baicker |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Marianne Bertrand |
Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Raj Chetty |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Judith Chevalier |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
There is short run predictability but consistently on a given day is a high standard.
|
||||
Janet Currie |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
David Cutler |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
I suspect 'very few' is an important qualifier.
|
||||
Angus Deaton |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
Provided "very few" includes the minority of hedge fund traders who clearly can.
|
||||
Darrell Duffie |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Despite attempts, there is no solid empirical evidence or convincing theoretical support for the contrary view.
|
||||
Aaron Edlin |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
Randomness is the best ex ante explanation of a given stock's movement on a given day.
-see background information here |
||||
Barry Eichengreen |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Ray Fair |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Pinelopi Goldberg |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Claudia Goldin |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
If even a few could predict that well then there would be little volatility and these "geniuses" would be very rich.
|
||||
Austan Goolsbee |
Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
We have at least 10,000 research papers establishing this one as a fact
|
||||
Michael Greenstone |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Robert Hall |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Bengt Holmström |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
Answer assumes that no public information is unaccounted for, because stock market is closed.
|
||||
Caroline Hoxby |
Stanford | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
Kenneth Judd |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
This is the conclusion of the empirical evidence I have seen.
|
||||
Anil Kashyap |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
Everyone should have to read Ken French's Presidential Address to the American Finance Association on the perils of active investing.
-see background information here |
||||
Pete Klenow |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Predictable anomalies are surely a small part of daily variance. Long term predictability seems greater (Campbell-Shiller).
-see background information here |
||||
Edward Lazear |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Markets may be far from perfect, but the literature supports that the current price is the best predictor of tomorrow's price.
|
||||
Jonathan Levin |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Hard one to answer - probably depends on interpretation of "very few" and "consistently".
|
||||
William Nordhaus |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
Tough question because of details. But yes. This is well studied and subject to small, low-yield, and transient anomalies.
|
||||
Maurice Obstfeld |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
The evidence supports this claim, though one can't infer that stock prices always equal reasonable forecasts of discounted future dividends.
|
||||
Cecilia Rouse |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
The informational requirements are too high given the many factors and random shocks that can occur on any given day.
|
||||
Emmanuel Saez |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
José Scheinkman |
Columbia University | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Richard Schmalensee |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
The evidence on this one seems overwhelming.
|
||||
Hyun Song Shin |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
James Stock |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Nancy Stokey |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Richard Thaler |
Chicago Booth | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
Christopher Udry |
Northwestern | Bio/Vote History | ||
There may be rare moments when movements of specific stocks are predictable, but these are fleeting and will yield profit to only a few.
|
||||
Luigi Zingales |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
Question B Participant Responses
Participant | University | Vote | Confidence | Bio/Vote History |
---|---|---|---|---|
Daron Acemoglu |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Joseph Altonji |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Alan Auerbach |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
David Autor |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
We were in a bubble. There were not enough future profits in the world to justify those prices.
|
||||
Katherine Baicker |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Marianne Bertrand |
Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Raj Chetty |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Judith Chevalier |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
The definition of plausibly is part of the issue---
|
||||
Janet Currie |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
This is not my area of expertise.
|
||||
David Cutler |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
Ex post events suggest otherwise.
|
||||
Angus Deaton |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
You mean there was no bubble?
|
||||
Darrell Duffie |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Expected cash flows were hard to estimate. See Pastor and Veronesi. An ex ante (1999) poll would be very interesting!
-see background information here |
||||
Aaron Edlin |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
Are we still arguing over whether the internet bubble was a bubble? I thought it was at the time and have never thought otherwise.
|
||||
Barry Eichengreen |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Ray Fair |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Pinelopi Goldberg |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Claudia Goldin |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
The Q is still oddly worded, but appears to ask whether the dot.com bubble was a bubble. I guess I think it was.
|
||||
Austan Goolsbee |
Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
?
We know that there was a bubble and most of them went out of business.
|
||||
Michael Greenstone |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
It is always easiest to make these judgments ex post, which of course, undermines their meaning.
|
||||
Robert Hall |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Turns on the interpretation of "plausible." My Ely Lecture made the case that eBay's valuation satisfied a plausible discounted div model.
-see background information here |
||||
Bengt Holmström |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Caroline Hoxby |
Stanford | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
Kenneth Judd |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
"Plausible" is a fuzzy term. Asset pricing theories concern averages, not events. If a 10-1 horse wins, does that mean the odds were wrong?
|
||||
Anil Kashyap |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
Never could figure out how pets.com, webvan and various other dotcoms could have ever made money.
|
||||
Pete Klenow |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Edward Lazear |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
In cases where ex post, something turns out to be a bubble, it is tough to say that ex ante expectations were plausible.
|
||||
Jonathan Levin |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
William Nordhaus |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
Even at the time, it was clear that these firms would have to earn most of GDP to rationalize their stock prices.
|
||||
Maurice Obstfeld |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
This episode was a classic case of contagious overoptimism.
|
||||
Cecilia Rouse |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
This is but one interpretation; a bubble would be another....
|
||||
Emmanuel Saez |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
José Scheinkman |
Columbia University | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Richard Schmalensee |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
I haven't seen an analysis of this for dot.coms in aggregate, but many of their valuations were truly nutty.
|
||||
Hyun Song Shin |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
James Stock |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Nancy Stokey |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
Asset prices are extremely volatile, and "explaining" this fact as variations in the price of risk seems close to tautological.
|
||||
Richard Thaler |
Chicago Booth | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
Christopher Udry |
Northwestern | Bio/Vote History | ||
The key is to define "plausible expectations". It is likely that widespread overconfidence contributed to the price rise.
|
||||
Luigi Zingales |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|