Question A:
The association between health and economic growth in poor countries primarily involves faster growth generating better health, rather than the other way around.
Responses
© 2025. Kent A. Clark Center for Global Markets.
19%
5%
2%
12%
19%
31%
12%
Responses weighted by each expert's confidence
© 2025. Kent A. Clark Center for Global Markets.
6%
14%
12%
41%
27%
Question B:
The decline in the fraction of people with incomes under, say, $1 per day is a good measure of whether well-being is improving among low-income populations.
Responses
© 2025. Kent A. Clark Center for Global Markets.
19%
2%
2%
24%
14%
31%
7%
Responses weighted by each expert's confidence
© 2025. Kent A. Clark Center for Global Markets.
3%
31%
15%
36%
14%
Question A Participant Responses
Participant |
University |
Vote |
Confidence |
Bio/Vote History |
---|---|---|---|---|
![]() Daron Acemoglu |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
Some estimates suggest effects from health to GDP, but the magnitudes are small. Considerable evidence exists on income to health channel
|
||||
![]() Alberto Alesina |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Joseph Altonji |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Alan Auerbach |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() David Autor |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Katherine Baicker |
University of Chicago | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
![]() Abhijit Banerjee |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
This is ill posed.I would guess that the likely reason for correlation is a third variable, like effective governance, which affects both
|
||||
![]() Marianne Bertrand |
Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Markus Brunnermeier |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
Historically one often sees first child mortality going down, before growth really picks up.
|
||||
![]() Raj Chetty |
Harvard | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
![]() Judith Chevalier |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
I suspect this is the primary channel, but there is some evidence the other way.
-see background information here |
||||
![]() David Cutler |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
There is literature both ways on this.
|
||||
![]() Angus Deaton |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
China is the obvious counterexample.
|
||||
![]() Darrell Duffie |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Yes, that seems right, but perhaps the answer changes for pre-historic societies.
|
||||
![]() Aaron Edlin |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Barry Eichengreen |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
I'm voting on the basis of the "primarily," since both directions are important.
|
||||
![]() Liran Einav |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Ray Fair |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Amy Finkelstein |
MIT | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
![]() Pinelopi Goldberg |
Yale | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
![]() Austan Goolsbee |
Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Michael Greenstone |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
this seems right on average but negative externalities like air pollution mean the relationship is not straightforward
-see background information here |
||||
Robert Hall |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Thanks to products from advanced countries, poor countries have had huge improvements in longevity without much income growth.
|
||||
![]() Oliver Hart |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
Better health can surely increase productivity and hence growth but it is hard to believe that the causation mainly goes this way.
|
||||
![]() Bengt Holmström |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Caroline Hoxby |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Hilary Hoynes |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Kenneth Judd |
Stanford | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
![]() Steven Kaplan |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Anil Kashyap |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
seems plausible that other factors ("institutions") could be driving both
|
||||
![]() Pete Klenow |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
![]() Jonathan Levin |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Eric Maskin |
Harvard | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
![]() William Nordhaus |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Emmanuel Saez |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Larry Samuelson |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
In some cases, health outcomes have improved without significant income growth, and it is difficult to say that the causality runs one way.
|
||||
![]() José Scheinkman |
Columbia University | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
![]() Richard Schmalensee |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Carl Shapiro |
Berkeley | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
![]() Robert Shimer |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
There is some evidence that the relationship goes in both directions. Unclear which effect is stronger.
|
||||
![]() Richard Thaler |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Christopher Udry |
Northwestern | Bio/Vote History | ||
Both directions of casualty operate, but the weight of evidence is that income to health has a stronger effect.
|
Question B Participant Responses
Participant |
University |
Vote |
Confidence |
Bio/Vote History |
---|---|---|---|---|
![]() Daron Acemoglu |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
$1 a day is an arbitrary measure. It is informative about the bottom, but not about living standards among low middle income households.
|
||||
![]() Alberto Alesina |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Joseph Altonji |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Alan Auerbach |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() David Autor |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
It's an okay start, but one could do much better! Why use a binary measure?
|
||||
![]() Katherine Baicker |
University of Chicago | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
![]() Abhijit Banerjee |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Marianne Bertrand |
Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Markus Brunnermeier |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
As population grows a declining fraction does not automatically imply a decline in number of people. Also, one has to correct for PPP and ..
|
||||
![]() Raj Chetty |
Harvard | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
![]() Judith Chevalier |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
I agree more than I disagree, but there are limitations to this measure.
|
||||
![]() David Cutler |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Angus Deaton |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
It is too incomplete, and too badly measured.
|
||||
![]() Darrell Duffie |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Aaron Edlin |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Barry Eichengreen |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Liran Einav |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Ray Fair |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Amy Finkelstein |
MIT | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
![]() Pinelopi Goldberg |
Yale | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
![]() Austan Goolsbee |
Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Michael Greenstone |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Robert Hall |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
There's more to the issue, but under the Inada condition, we care desperately about people whose log consumption is close to minus infinity.
|
||||
![]() Oliver Hart |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
It is probably not a great measure unless it incorporates the prices of local goods. Also it misses out on non-traded goods and services.
|
||||
![]() Bengt Holmström |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Caroline Hoxby |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
If this were $1 of consumption and not income, yes. Also if we mean "income" inferred from consumption, yes. But cash income is poor measure
|
||||
![]() Hilary Hoynes |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Kenneth Judd |
Stanford | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
![]() Steven Kaplan |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
The reduction in poverty worldwide so measured is a great success story over the last 35 years.
|
||||
![]() Anil Kashyap |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Pete Klenow |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
![]() Jonathan Levin |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Eric Maskin |
Harvard | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
![]() William Nordhaus |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Emmanuel Saez |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
![]() Larry Samuelson |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
There are many other measures that should also be used, but this measure is informative.
|
||||
![]() José Scheinkman |
Columbia University | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
![]() Richard Schmalensee |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
Obviously not a perfect measure, but intuitive and should capture major trends.
|
||||
![]() Carl Shapiro |
Berkeley | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
![]() Robert Shimer |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
It is a good measure, but it is flawed and it is not the only measure.
|
||||
![]() Richard Thaler |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
As usual, the key word here is "good".
|
||||
![]() Christopher Udry |
Northwestern | Bio/Vote History | ||
"Good" may be too strong. Income is incomplete, difficult to define and measure, hard to compare across populations... But it's something.
|