Alberto Alesina, a founding member of the IGM economic experts panel, passed away in May 2020 – a sad loss for the whole research community. As the remembrances posted by the IGM directors on our website illustrate, Alberto was a fantastic economist, a wonderful person and a friend to many of the panelists.
To mark the sad occasion, we invited both our US and European panels to express their views on aspects of Alberto’s work. We asked the experts whether they agreed or disagreed with the following statements, and, if so, how strongly and with what degree of confidence:
(a) Political conflict plays a key role in shaping economic decisions, policies and outcomes.
US panel: (b) The US has a smaller social welfare system than other rich countries in part because it is more heterogeneous by race and ethnicity.
European panel: (b) Most European countries have larger social welfare systems than the United States in part because the latter is more heterogeneous by race and ethnicity.
Of our 43 US experts, 40 participated in this survey; of our 45 European experts, 39 participated – for a total of 79 expert reactions.
Political conflict and the economy
On the first statement, both panels are unanimous that political conflict plays a key role in shaping economic decisions, policies and outcomes. Weighted by each expert’s confidence in their response, 69% of the US panel strongly agree, and 31% agree; and 56% of the European panel strongly agree, and 44% agree.
Among the short comments that the experts are able to include in their responses, Charles Wyplosz at the Graduate Institute, Geneva, notes: ‘This is what Alberto Alesina taught us.’ Caroline Hoxby at Stanford says: ‘My insightful and powerfully-minded colleague Alberto Alesina is responsible for much of the evidence on this point. Read his masterful work.’ Alberto’s Harvard colleague Pol Antras adds: ‘Thank you very everything you taught us, Alberto. Rest in Peace.’
Aaron Edlin at Berkeley points out that: ‘Where there are decisions to be made, there is politics, and where there is politics, there is conflict.’ And Larry Samuelson at Yale explains: ‘Political actors respond to incentives; conflicting incentives play a key role in shaping economic policy and activity.’
A couple of wrinkles come from Franklin Allen at Imperial, who comments: ‘In most countries, this is the case, in my view. In some totalitarian countries, it is not the case though’; while Peter Neary at Oxford states: ‘Hardly controversial in itself. More so is its importance relative to ideology, history, and deep economic forces.’
Anil Kashyap at Chicago provides a link to Alberto’s paper on macroeconomics and politics; while Pete Klenow at Stanford references Alberto’s paper with European panelist Eliana La Ferrara on the positive and negative effects of ethnic diversity on economic policies and outcomes.
Ethnic heterogeneity and support for social welfare systems
The second statement was framed slightly differently in the way it was put to the two panels, but the central idea was the same: whether the fact that the United States is more heterogeneous by race and ethnicity than most European countries is the reason for its smaller social welfare system.
On this issue, views are more varied: of the US panel (weighted by each expert’s confidence in their response), 17% strongly agree, 69% agree, 13% are uncertain, and 1% disagree. The European panel agrees considerably less (though still a majority), expresses more uncertainty (a third), and features more disagreement: 15% strongly agree, 40% agree, 33% are uncertain, and 13% disagree.
Among panelists who agree, Eric Maskin at Harvard says: ‘Alberto Alesina’s writings establish both points quite persuasively’; while Pol Antras comments: ‘I think Alberto convinced most of us that this is part of the reason. Of course, there are many other reasons why.’
Several other panelists mention some of those other reasons, Peter Neary, himself sadly no longer with us, adds: ‘The sad passing of Alberto Alesina reminds us of his work showing this; though ideology and public perceptions of heterogeneity also matter.’ Larry Samuelson comments: ‘The evidence is that people are more supportive of programs whose benefits go to “people like me”.’ Christopher Udry at Northwestern states: ‘But put it differently. It’s not diversity itself. It’s racism.’
A historical perspective comes from Daron Acemoglu at MIT, who says: ‘But unclear how much of this is because of the current effect of these variables or the historical, long-lasting compromises they induced.’ And Angus Deaton at Princeton notes: ‘I think it is less to do with heterogeneity, than with the legacy of slavery and white versus black.’
Among panelists who are say they are uncertain or disagree, Markus Brunnermeier at Princeton notes: ‘Empirical evidence points to it, but Canada might be a counterexample.’ Richard Blundell at University College London asks: ‘Isn’t it more about the underlying inequalities by race and ethnicity in the US rather than race and ethnicity itself?’ And Aaron Edlin concludes: ‘Looking across states with casual empiricism, many of the more diverse appear to have stronger social welfare programs. This gives me pause.’
Pete Klenow and Christian Leuz at Chicago both mention Alberto’s paper with Edward Glaeser and Bruce Sacerdote asking the question: why doesn’t the United States have a European-style welfare state? And Christian directs us to further papers by Alberto and colleagues on immigration and preferences for redistribution.
All comments made by the experts are in the full survey results.
Romesh Vaitilingam
@econromesh
Question A:
Political conflict plays a key role in shaping economic decisions, policies and outcomes.
Responses
Responses weighted by each expert's confidence
Question B:
The US has a smaller social welfare system than other rich countries in part because it is more heterogeneous by race and ethnicity.
Responses
Responses weighted by each expert's confidence
Question A Participant Responses
Question B Participant Responses
Participant | University | Vote | Confidence | Bio/Vote History |
---|---|---|---|---|
Daron Acemoglu |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
But unclear how much of this is because of the current effect of these variables or the historical, long-lasting compromises they induced.
|
||||
Joseph Altonji |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Alan Auerbach |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
David Autor |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Katherine Baicker |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Abhijit Banerjee |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Marianne Bertrand |
Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Markus Brunnermeier |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
Empirical evidence points to it, but Canada might be a counterexample.
|
||||
Raj Chetty |
Harvard | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
Judith Chevalier |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
David Cutler |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
Alberto Alesina taught us about this. I miss him already.
|
||||
Angus Deaton |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
I think it is less to do with heterogeneity, than with the legacy of slavery and white v black.
|
||||
Darrell Duffie |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
I'm not expert enough to handle this question.
|
||||
Aaron Edlin |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
Looking across states with casual empiricism, many of the more diverse appear to have stronger social welfare programs. This gives me pause.
|
||||
Barry Eichengreen |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Liran Einav |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Ray Fair |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Amy Finkelstein |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Pinelopi Goldberg |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Austan Goolsbee |
Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
Depressing thought of the day
|
||||
Michael Greenstone |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Robert Hall |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
That is what some experts have made a case for
|
||||
Oliver Hart |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Bengt Holmström |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
Plays probably some role, but I don't know that one can identify it's significance. So many other factors.
|
||||
Caroline Hoxby |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Economics has lost one of its greatest thinkers with our losing Alberto Alesina.
|
||||
Hilary Hoynes |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Kenneth Judd |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
I would add income and cultural heterogeneity.
|
||||
Steven Kaplan |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Anil Kashyap |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Pete Klenow |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Jonathan Levin |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Eric Maskin |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
Alberto Alesina's writings establish both points quite persuasively.
|
||||
William Nordhaus |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Maurice Obstfeld |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Emmanuel Saez |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Larry Samuelson |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
The evidence is that people are more supported of programs whose benefits go to "people like me".
|
||||
José Scheinkman |
Columbia University | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Richard Schmalensee |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Carl Shapiro |
Berkeley | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
Robert Shimer |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
The question states "in part". Another question is "how big a part"?
|
||||
James Stock |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Richard Thaler |
Chicago Booth | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
Christopher Udry |
Northwestern | Bio/Vote History | ||
But put it differently. It's not diversity itself. It's racism.
|