US

Overheating

Amid fierce public debates about the size of the Biden administration’s coronavirus protection and stimulus package, we invited our US panel to express their views on the likelihood of the economy ‘overheating’ as a result of the current stance of fiscal and monetary policy. We asked the experts whether they agreed or disagreed with the following statement, and, if so, how strongly and with what degree of confidence:

The current combination of US fiscal and monetary policy poses a serious risk of prolonged higher inflation.

Overheating

Of our 43 experts, 38 participated in this survey, and the results indicate considerable uncertainty and differences in views. Weighted by each expert’s confidence in their response, 33% agree with the statement, 36% are uncertain, 26% disagree, and 4% strongly disagree. The short comments that the experts are able to include when they participate in the survey provide more details on different perspectives.

Among those who agree that there are risks of prolonged higher inflation, Steven Kaplan at Chicago states: ‘Poses a risk, but much uncertainty about whether that risk will be realized’; while his colleague Anil Kashyap comments: ‘Poses for sure. We don’t know much about how inflation expectations are formed; if they become unhinged, watch out.’ Markus Brunnermeier at Princeton adds: ‘While sharp price spikes might be transitory, they can translate into lasting higher inflation if one isn’t watchful.’

Ray Fair at Yale points us to his own analysis of the issue: ‘I have a recent paper on this, “What Do Price Equations Say About Future Inflation?” using an econometric approach.’ Pete Klenow at Stanford also directs us to some further reading with a consensus view on inflation prospects: ‘Modest in magnitude: ~20 bps over the next 5 years and ~10 bps over the next 10 years, according to the Survey of Professional Forecasters.’

Darrell Duffie at Stanford remarks: ‘A bit higher inflation would be good. The risk of much higher inflation involves a tradeoff. Better infrastructure, for instance, is needed.’ Similarly, Abhijit Banerjee at MIT, who says he is uncertain, notes: ‘I am not sure that slightly higher inflation would be a bad thing by the way. The question seems to lean that way.’

Among other panelists who express uncertainty, Judith Chevalier at Yale notes: ‘The TIP-Treasury spread does not suggest extreme inflation expectations at the moment.’ And Austan Goolsbee at Chicago comments: ‘There wasn’t prolonged inflation with unemployment at 3.5%. Why would it be prolonged when, apples-to-apples, it is double that?’

Kenneth Judd at Stanford points to a source of uncertainty: ‘It is unclear if current conditions indicating overheating, such as the so-called labor shortage, are temporary or important beyond summer.’ And Larry Samuelson at Yale returns to the issue of uncertainty about expectations: ‘It is remarkable that inflation has hitherto been mild. It might be temporary, but inflationary expectations are hard to dampen.’

Richard Thaler at Chicago cautions: ‘Any strong opinion is misplaced.’ And Eric Maskin at Harvard concludes: ‘There appears to be significant disagreement among experts on this point. I don’t know enough myself to say one way or the other.’

Daron Acemoglu at MIT is uncertain about how the statement describes potential inflationary dangers: ‘Inflation is undoubtedly more likely now than it has been for 20 years. But the qualifiers “serious” and “prolonged” are too strong.’ This perspective is shared by Richard Schmalensee at Yale, who disagrees with the statement, arguing: ‘“Serious” and “prolonged” seem a reach.’

Several others who disagree suggest that monetary policy can react effectively should the need arise. Aaron Edlin at Berkeley says: ‘Current policy does not by itself pose that risk because future monetary policy can be changed swiftly.’ William Nordhaus at Yale concurs: ‘Fed can and will react to prevent this syndrome were it to threaten.’ And Robert Hall at Stanford, the only panelist to vote ‘strongly disagree’, states: ‘Monetary policy is firmly committed to keeping inflation under control and has the means to do it.’

Similarly, Jose Scheinkman at Columbia notes: ‘Prolonged higher inflation would require a very inattentive Fed.’ And Barry Eichengreen at Berkeley comments: ‘If “current combination” means accommodating monetary policy now but higher interest rates if higher inflation materializes, then why “sustained”.’

Finally, James Stock at Harvard looks to potential risks further down the road: ‘The risk is more at long horizons with our unsustainable debt path, than at one-two years.’

All comments made by the experts are in the full survey results.

Romesh Vaitilingam
@econromesh
June 2021

 

The current combination of US fiscal and monetary policy poses a serious risk of prolonged higher inflation.

Responses weighted by each expert's confidence

Participant University Vote Confidence Bio/Vote History
Acemoglu
Daron Acemoglu
MIT
Uncertain
3
Bio/Vote History
Inflation is undoubtedly more likely now than it has been for 20 years. But the qualifiers "serious" and "prolonged" are too strong.
Altonji
Joseph Altonji
Yale
Uncertain
3
Bio/Vote History
Auerbach
Alan Auerbach
Berkeley
Agree
3
Bio/Vote History
Autor
David Autor
MIT
Uncertain
3
Bio/Vote History
Baicker
Katherine Baicker
University of Chicago Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Banerjee
Abhijit Banerjee
MIT
Uncertain
6
Bio/Vote History
I am not sure that slightly higher inflation would be a bad thing btw. The question seems to lean that way.
Bertrand
Marianne Bertrand
Chicago
Uncertain
4
Bio/Vote History
Brunnermeier
Markus Brunnermeier
Princeton
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
While sharp price spikes might be transitory, they can translate in lasting higher inflation if one isn’t watchful.
Chetty
Raj Chetty
Harvard
Uncertain
5
Bio/Vote History
Chevalier
Judith Chevalier
Yale
Uncertain
4
Bio/Vote History
The TIP-Treasury spread does not suggest extreme inflation expecations at the moment.
Cutler
David Cutler
Harvard
Disagree
5
Bio/Vote History
Deaton
Angus Deaton
Princeton
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Duffie
Darrell Duffie
Stanford
Agree
9
Bio/Vote History
A bit higher inflation would be good. The risk of much higher inflation involves a tradeoff. Better infrastructure, for instance, is needed.
Edlin
Aaron Edlin
Berkeley
Disagree
6
Bio/Vote History
Current policy does not by itself pose that risk because future monetary policy can be changed swiftly.
Eichengreen
Barry Eichengreen
Berkeley
Disagree
5
Bio/Vote History
If "current combination" means acccomodating mon policy now but higher interest rates if higher inflation materializes, then why "sustained"
Einav
Liran Einav
Stanford
Uncertain
1
Bio/Vote History
Fair
Ray Fair
Yale
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
I have a recent paper on this, "What Do Price Equations Say About Future Inflation?" using an econometric approach.
-see background information here
Finkelstein
Amy Finkelstein
MIT Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Goldberg
Pinelopi Goldberg
Yale
Uncertain
6
Bio/Vote History
Goolsbee
Austan Goolsbee
Chicago
Uncertain
6
Bio/Vote History
There wasn’t prolonged inflation with unemployment at 3.5%. Why would it be prolonged when, apples-to-apples, it is double that?
Greenstone
Michael Greenstone
University of Chicago
Uncertain
4
Bio/Vote History
Hall
Robert Hall
Stanford
Strongly Disagree
8
Bio/Vote History
Monetary policy is firmly committed to keeping inflation under control and has the means to do it
Hart
Oliver Hart
Harvard
Uncertain
5
Bio/Vote History
Holmström
Bengt Holmström
MIT
Agree
4
Bio/Vote History
Hoxby
Caroline Hoxby
Stanford Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Hoynes
Hilary Hoynes
Berkeley
Disagree
8
Bio/Vote History
Judd
Kenneth Judd
Stanford
Uncertain
6
Bio/Vote History
It is unclear if current conditions indicating overheating, such as the so-called labor shortage, are temporary or important beyond summer.
Kaplan
Steven Kaplan
Chicago Booth
Agree
3
Bio/Vote History
Poses a risk, but much uncertainty about whether that risk will be realized.
Kashyap
Anil Kashyap
Chicago Booth
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
poses for sure. we don't know much about how inflation expectations are formed, if they become unhinged watch out
Klenow
Pete Klenow
Stanford
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Modest in magnitude: ~20 bps over the next 5 years and ~10 bps over the next 10 years according to the Survey of Professional Forecasters.
-see background information here
Levin
Jonathan Levin
Stanford
Uncertain
3
Bio/Vote History
Maskin
Eric Maskin
Harvard
Uncertain
3
Bio/Vote History
There appears to be significant disagreement among experts on this point. I don't know enough myself to say one way or the other.
Nordhaus
William Nordhaus
Yale
Disagree
8
Bio/Vote History
Fed can and will react to prevent this syndrome were it to threaten.
Obstfeld
Maurice Obstfeld
Berkeley
Disagree
6
Bio/Vote History
Saez
Emmanuel Saez
Berkeley
Uncertain
5
Bio/Vote History
Samuelson
Larry Samuelson
Yale
Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
It is remarkable that inflation has hitherto been mild. It might be temporary, but inflationary expectations are hard to dampen.
Scheinkman
José Scheinkman
Columbia University
Disagree
5
Bio/Vote History
Prolonged higher inflation would require a very inattentive FED.
Schmalensee
Richard Schmalensee
MIT
Disagree
4
Bio/Vote History
"Serious" and "prolonged" seem a reach.
Shapiro
Carl Shapiro
Berkeley Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Shimer
Robert Shimer
University of Chicago
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Stock
James Stock
Harvard
Disagree
3
Bio/Vote History
The risk is more at long horizons with our unsustainable debt path, than at one-two years.
Thaler
Richard Thaler
Chicago Booth
Uncertain
1
Bio/Vote History
Any strong opinion is misplaced.
Udry
Christopher Udry
Northwestern Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History