US

Inflation, Market Power, and Price Controls

With sharply rising US inflation prompting debate about the potential role of powerful firms in driving up prices and whether antitrust interventions and/or price controls may be an effective policy response, we invited our US panel to express their views. We asked the experts whether they agreed or disagreed with the following statements, and, if so, how strongly and with what degree of confidence:

a) A significant factor behind today’s higher US inflation is dominant corporations in uncompetitive markets taking advantage of their market power to raise prices in order to increase their profit margins.

b) Antitrust interventions could successfully reduce US inflation over the next 12 months.

c) Price controls as deployed in the 1970s could successfully reduce US inflation over the next 12 months.

Market power and inflation

Of our 43 US experts, 41 participated in this survey. On the first statement about firms with market power pushing up inflation, over three-quarters of the panel disagree. Weighted by each expert’s confidence in their response, 3% of the panel strongly agree, 7% agree, 12% are uncertain, 52% disagree, and 27% strongly disagree.

More details on the experts’ views come in the short comments that they are able to include when they participate in the survey. Among those who say they are uncertain, Daron Acemoglu at MIT notes: ‘The US has a big business problem, with various pernicious effects. But it is not clear whether this has been a major factor in inflation.’ Larry Samuelson at Yale adds: ‘Corporate market power leads to higher prices, but it is not clear this is the dominant force behind the increased inflation rate.’ And Austan Goolsbee at Chicago comments: ‘Margins are up but not by enough to explain inflation.’

Among panelists who disagree, Christopher Udry at Northwestern replies: ‘Market structure obviously interacts with shocks to affect inflation, but unlikely that this is first order now.’ Others point to mechanisms by which market structure, firms’ costs, prices and inflation may interact. For example, Judith Chevalier at Yale says: ‘Pass-through of both cost shocks and demand shocks clearly differ in industries with versus without market power’, adding a link to a study of pass-through as an economic tool. And Eric Maskin at Harvard notes: ‘Theory suggests that monopolists respond less to changes in costs than pure competitors do – so market power doesn’t seem a likely culprit.’

Robert Hall at Stanford declares: ‘The proposition is an elementary confusion of levels and changes – market power causes high prices, not rising prices.’ Richard Schmalensee at MIT concurs: ‘Market power yields high prices, not rapidly rising prices.’ And Markus Brunnermeier at Princeton suggests: ‘Many firms have market power due to supply shortages, which prevents competitors from expanding. Dominant tech firms didn’t push prices up.’

Several experts refer to the different timescales between changes in market power and changes in inflation. Anil Kashyap at Chicago links to recent New York Fed data on inflation expectations, commenting: ‘Inflation has shot up, could market power really have changed much and why would firms be leaving money on the table before?’ David Autor at MIT remarks: ‘I don’t see the logic: US markets have been concentrating for decades but high inflation is less than one year old.’ And linking to St Louis Fed data, Pete Klenow at Stanford observes: ‘Labor’s share of income seems to have risen in 2021, not fallen.’

Antitrust interventions

On the second statement about whether antitrust interventions could reduce inflation, more than four in five panelists disagree. Weighted by each expert’s confidence in their response, 4% of the panel agree, 12% are uncertain, 38% disagree, and 46% strongly disagree.

Among the comments, Larry Samuelson at Yale states: ‘Antitrust intervention is warranted in many markets, but again it is not clear this will reduce the rate of inflation.’ Robert Hall protests: ‘Many interventions are on behalf of high-cost disappointed rivals, so the interventions tend to raise prices.’ And Austan Goolsbee comments: ‘Seems dubious as a national level policy. In some specific industries, it could reduce pricing power.’

Several experts who disagree note that antitrust actions typically operate on a very different timescale to policies to control inflation. Markus Brunnermeier responds: ‘Antitrust works at a different frequency.’ William Nordhaus at Yale says: ‘Couldn’t even get the case filed in 12 months.’ Daron Acemoglu adds: ‘Even if excessive monopoly power was a contributing factor, antitrust couldn’t act that fast.’

Others who disagree suggest various caveats. David Autor remarks: ‘US has a competition problem – but I don’t see it closely connected to current inflation.’ Richard Schmalensee explains: ‘Charging high prices or even increasing prices is not an antitrust violation. Threats might have some slight effect in a few places.’ And Jose Scheinkman at Columbia suggests: ‘However, better antitrust policy could lead to productivity improvements in the long run.’

Price controls

On the third statement about whether 1970s-style price controls could reduce inflation, a smaller majority disagrees than on the first two questions. Weighted by each expert’s confidence in their response, 24% of the panel agree, 11% are uncertain, 49% disagree, and 16% strongly disagree.

While nearly a quarter of the panelists agree that price controls could reduce inflation, several make clear that they don’t necessarily think that reintroducing them should actually happen. Darrell Duffie at Stanford explains: ‘Barring illegal price setting, this seems to be mechanically true. A more interesting question is whether price controls are a good idea!’ Eric Maskin observes: ‘I imagine that price controls could restrain inflation – but that doesn’t mean such controls are a good idea. And David Autor adds: ‘Price controls can of course control prices – but they’re a terrible idea!’

Others who agree provide more detail on why price controls might be unwise. Aaron Edlin at Berkeley comments: ‘Price controls could temporarily reduce inflation at cost of shortages and possibly later inflation.’ Oliver Hart at Yale says: ‘They could reduce inflation but the consequence would be shortages and rationing.’ Kenneth Judd at Stanford remarks: ‘Yes, it could reduce inflation over the short run – but only temporarily – just as the 1971 controls did. Too much money creation.’ And Jose Scheinkman adds: ‘Could lower measured inflation but would generate inefficiencies and cause even higher inflation when controls are lifted (see US 1974).’

Comments by panelists who say they are uncertain reflect similar concerns. James Stock at Harvard argues: ‘There might be some ephemeral success because of the way inflation is measured, but longer-run, price controls would be ineffective.’ Abhijit Banerjee at MIT states: ‘I worry that the implementation will be a huge challenge, as it was in the 1970s.’ And William Nordhaus notes: ‘Perhaps could reduce inflation in short run as 1970s. Would only cause more shortages and a terrible idea.’

Some panelists who disagree with the statement point to experiences with price controls in the 1970s and elsewhere. Joseph Altonji at Yale says: ‘Wage and price controls in the early 70s did little good.’ Barry Eichengreen at Berkeley agrees: ‘As deployed in the 1970s? In the 1970s they were not particularly effective.’ And linking to evidence from Argentina on the impact of targeted price controls for supermarket products, Pete Klenow explains: ‘And they would distort price signals.’

Finally, there are some further thoughts on likely damaging effects of price controls. Robert Shimer at Chicago says: ‘Price controls could affect measured prices, but only by creating shortages, i.e. mismeasurement of true prices (including queues, waiting, etc).’ Maurice Obstfeld at Berkeley adds: ‘Even if there were a negative effect on measured inflation (as in the early 1970s), shortages would raise shadow inflation.’ And Anil Kashyap concludes: ‘They would have to be draconian with fewer exceptions and even then the longer-term effectiveness would be highly doubtful.’

All comments made by the experts are in the full survey results.

Romesh Vaitilingam
@econromesh
February 2022

Question A:

A significant factor behind today’s higher US inflation is dominant corporations in uncompetitive markets taking advantage of their market power to raise prices in order to increase their profit margins.

Responses weighted by each expert's confidence

Question B:

Antitrust interventions could successfully reduce US inflation over the next 12 months.

Responses weighted by each expert's confidence

Question C:

Price controls as deployed in the 1970s could successfully reduce US inflation over the next 12 months.

Responses weighted by each expert's confidence

Question A Participant Responses

Participant University Vote Confidence Bio/Vote History
Acemoglu
Daron Acemoglu
MIT
Uncertain
3
Bio/Vote History
The US has a big business problem, with various pernicious effects. But it is not clear whether this has been a major factor in inflation.
Altonji
Joseph Altonji
Yale
Disagree
8
Bio/Vote History
Auerbach
Alan Auerbach
Berkeley
Disagree
7
Bio/Vote History
Autor
David Autor
MIT
Disagree
7
Bio/Vote History
I don't see the logic: U.S. markets have been concentrating for decades but high inflation is < one year old
Baicker
Katherine Baicker
University of Chicago Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Banerjee
Abhijit Banerjee
MIT
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Bertrand
Marianne Bertrand
Chicago
Uncertain
1
Bio/Vote History
Brunnermeier
Markus Brunnermeier
Princeton
Uncertain
3
Bio/Vote History
Many firms have market paper due to supply shortages which prevents competitors to expand. Dominant Tech firms didn't push prices up.
Chetty
Raj Chetty
Harvard Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Chevalier
Judith Chevalier
Yale
Uncertain
7
Bio/Vote History
Pass-through of both cost shocks & demand shocks clearly differ in industries with vs without market power.
-see background information here
Cutler
David Cutler
Harvard
Disagree
4
Bio/Vote History
Deaton
Angus Deaton
Princeton
Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
Duffie
Darrell Duffie
Stanford
Uncertain
2
Bio/Vote History
To agree, one must also be able to explain why inflation has changed recently.
Edlin
Aaron Edlin
Berkeley
Strongly Disagree
7
Bio/Vote History
dominance has increased dramatically in last two years. When you hear hooves think horses not zebras. It is demand and supply.
Eichengreen
Barry Eichengreen
Berkeley
Disagree
5
Bio/Vote History
Einav
Liran Einav
Stanford
Disagree
3
Bio/Vote History
Fair
Ray Fair
Yale
Disagree
5
Bio/Vote History
Finkelstein
Amy Finkelstein
MIT
Disagree
2
Bio/Vote History
Goldberg
Pinelopi Goldberg
Yale
Disagree
9
Bio/Vote History
Goolsbee
Austan Goolsbee
Chicago
Uncertain
5
Bio/Vote History
Margins are up but not by enough to explain inflation.
Greenstone
Michael Greenstone
University of Chicago
Disagree
3
Bio/Vote History
Hall
Robert Hall
Stanford
Disagree
7
Bio/Vote History
The proposition is an elementary confusion of levels and changes--market power causes high prices , not rising prices.
Hart
Oliver Hart
Harvard
Disagree
7
Bio/Vote History
Holmström
Bengt Holmström
MIT
Strongly Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
Hoxby
Caroline Hoxby
Stanford
Strongly Disagree
10
Bio/Vote History
Hoynes
Hilary Hoynes
Berkeley
No Opinion
Bio/Vote History
Judd
Kenneth Judd
Stanford
Disagree
7
Bio/Vote History
I am sure some of this is going on but I doubt that it is a major contribution.
Kaplan
Steven Kaplan
Chicago Booth
Strongly Disagree
9
Bio/Vote History
Kashyap
Anil Kashyap
Chicago Booth
Strongly Disagree
9
Bio/Vote History
Inflation has shot up, could market power really have changed much and why would firms be leaving money on the table before?
-see background information here
Klenow
Pete Klenow
Stanford
Disagree
5
Bio/Vote History
Labor's share of income seems to have risen in 2021, not fallen.
-see background information here
Levin
Jonathan Levin
Stanford
Disagree
6
Bio/Vote History
Maskin
Eric Maskin
Harvard
Disagree
5
Bio/Vote History
Theory suggests that monopolists respond less to changes in costs than pure competitors do---so market power doesn't seem a likely culprit
Nordhaus
William Nordhaus
Yale
Disagree
8
Bio/Vote History
used cars? motels? beefsteaks? furniture?
Obstfeld
Maurice Obstfeld
Berkeley
Uncertain
6
Bio/Vote History
Saez
Emmanuel Saez
Berkeley
Disagree
3
Bio/Vote History
Samuelson
Larry Samuelson
Yale
Uncertain
1
Bio/Vote History
Corporate market power, which leads to higher prices, but it is not clear this is the dominant force behind the increased inflation rate.
Scheinkman
José Scheinkman
Columbia University
Disagree
8
Bio/Vote History
Schmalensee
Richard Schmalensee
MIT
Strongly Disagree
9
Bio/Vote History
Market power yields high prices, not rapidly rising prices.
Shapiro
Carl Shapiro
Berkeley
Strongly Disagree
8
Bio/Vote History
Shimer
Robert Shimer
University of Chicago
Strongly Disagree
8
Bio/Vote History
Stock
James Stock
Harvard
Disagree
4
Bio/Vote History
Thaler
Richard Thaler
Chicago Booth
Disagree
1
Bio/Vote History
As usual, "significant" is undefined, but it seems unlikely this is the main culprit.
Udry
Christopher Udry
Northwestern
Disagree
3
Bio/Vote History
Market structure obviously interacts with shocks to affect inflation, but unlikely that this is first order now.

Question B Participant Responses

Participant University Vote Confidence Bio/Vote History
Acemoglu
Daron Acemoglu
MIT
Disagree
3
Bio/Vote History
Even if excessive monopoly power was a contributing factor, antitrust couldn't act that fast.
Altonji
Joseph Altonji
Yale
Strongly Disagree
7
Bio/Vote History
Auerbach
Alan Auerbach
Berkeley
Disagree
7
Bio/Vote History
Autor
David Autor
MIT
Disagree
5
Bio/Vote History
U.S. has a competition problem -- but I don't see it closely connected to current inflation
Baicker
Katherine Baicker
University of Chicago Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Banerjee
Abhijit Banerjee
MIT
Uncertain
5
Bio/Vote History
Bertrand
Marianne Bertrand
Chicago
Uncertain
1
Bio/Vote History
Brunnermeier
Markus Brunnermeier
Princeton
Disagree
1
Bio/Vote History
Anti-trust works at a difference frequency.
Chetty
Raj Chetty
Harvard Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Chevalier
Judith Chevalier
Yale
Disagree
7
Bio/Vote History
Cutler
David Cutler
Harvard
Disagree
5
Bio/Vote History
Deaton
Angus Deaton
Princeton
Strongly Disagree
7
Bio/Vote History
Duffie
Darrell Duffie
Stanford
Agree
4
Bio/Vote History
Anti-trust actions against providers of goods and services with market power tend to lower their market prices.
Edlin
Aaron Edlin
Berkeley
Strongly Disagree
8
Bio/Vote History
Eichengreen
Barry Eichengreen
Berkeley
Uncertain
5
Bio/Vote History
Einav
Liran Einav
Stanford
Strongly Disagree
1
Bio/Vote History
Fair
Ray Fair
Yale
Disagree
5
Bio/Vote History
Finkelstein
Amy Finkelstein
MIT
Disagree
2
Bio/Vote History
Goldberg
Pinelopi Goldberg
Yale
Disagree
9
Bio/Vote History
Goolsbee
Austan Goolsbee
Chicago
Uncertain
5
Bio/Vote History
Seems dubious as a national level policy. In some specific industries it could reduce pricing power.
Greenstone
Michael Greenstone
University of Chicago
Disagree
4
Bio/Vote History
Hall
Robert Hall
Stanford
Disagree
7
Bio/Vote History
Many interventions are on behalf of high-cost disappointed rivals, so the interventions tend to raise prices
Hart
Oliver Hart
Harvard
Disagree
7
Bio/Vote History
Holmström
Bengt Holmström
MIT
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Hoxby
Caroline Hoxby
Stanford
Strongly Disagree
10
Bio/Vote History
Hoynes
Hilary Hoynes
Berkeley
Uncertain
8
Bio/Vote History
Judd
Kenneth Judd
Stanford
Strongly Disagree
8
Bio/Vote History
Antitrust actions take a long time to implement.
Kaplan
Steven Kaplan
Chicago Booth
Strongly Disagree
9
Bio/Vote History
Kashyap
Anil Kashyap
Chicago Booth
Strongly Disagree
7
Bio/Vote History
Klenow
Pete Klenow
Stanford
Disagree
3
Bio/Vote History
Levin
Jonathan Levin
Stanford
Strongly Disagree
8
Bio/Vote History
Maskin
Eric Maskin
Harvard
Disagree
5
Bio/Vote History
As I already said, I don't think market power is the problem here.
Nordhaus
William Nordhaus
Yale
Disagree
9
Bio/Vote History
Couldn't even get the case filed in 12 months.
Obstfeld
Maurice Obstfeld
Berkeley
Strongly Disagree
6
Bio/Vote History
Saez
Emmanuel Saez
Berkeley
Uncertain
3
Bio/Vote History
Samuelson
Larry Samuelson
Yale
Uncertain
1
Bio/Vote History
Antitrust intervention is warranted in many markets, but again it is not clear this will reduce the rate of inflation.
Scheinkman
José Scheinkman
Columbia University
Strongly Disagree
8
Bio/Vote History
However, better antitrust policy could lead to productivity improvements in the long run.
Schmalensee
Richard Schmalensee
MIT
Strongly Disagree
8
Bio/Vote History
Charging high prices or even increasing prices is not an antitrust violation. Threats might have some slight effect in a few places.
Shapiro
Carl Shapiro
Berkeley
Strongly Disagree
10
Bio/Vote History
Shimer
Robert Shimer
University of Chicago
Strongly Disagree
10
Bio/Vote History
Stock
James Stock
Harvard
Disagree
8
Bio/Vote History
Thaler
Richard Thaler
Chicago Booth
Strongly Disagree
3
Bio/Vote History
Here the undefined word is "successfully"
Udry
Christopher Udry
Northwestern
Disagree
3
Bio/Vote History

Question C Participant Responses

Participant University Vote Confidence Bio/Vote History
Acemoglu
Daron Acemoglu
MIT
Agree
3
Bio/Vote History
Effective price controls, by definition, would reduce price increases, but they would most probably create other huge distortions.
Altonji
Joseph Altonji
Yale
Disagree
6
Bio/Vote History
Wage and price controls in the early 70s did little good.
Auerbach
Alan Auerbach
Berkeley
Disagree
7
Bio/Vote History
Autor
David Autor
MIT
Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
Price controls can of course control prices -- but they're a terrible idea!
Baicker
Katherine Baicker
University of Chicago Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Banerjee
Abhijit Banerjee
MIT
Uncertain
5
Bio/Vote History
I worry that the implementation will be a huge challenge, as it was in the 1970s.
Bertrand
Marianne Bertrand
Chicago
Disagree
1
Bio/Vote History
Brunnermeier
Markus Brunnermeier
Princeton
Disagree
7
Bio/Vote History
Chetty
Raj Chetty
Harvard Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Chevalier
Judith Chevalier
Yale
Disagree
5
Bio/Vote History
Cutler
David Cutler
Harvard
Disagree
5
Bio/Vote History
Deaton
Angus Deaton
Princeton
Strongly Disagree
7
Bio/Vote History
Duffie
Darrell Duffie
Stanford
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Barring illegal price setting, this seems to be mechanically true. A more interesting question is whether price controls are a good idea!
Edlin
Aaron Edlin
Berkeley
Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
Price controls could temporarily reduce inflation at cost of shortages and possibly later inflation.
Eichengreen
Barry Eichengreen
Berkeley
Disagree
5
Bio/Vote History
As deployed in the 1970s? In the 1970s they were not particularly effective.
Einav
Liran Einav
Stanford
Disagree
1
Bio/Vote History
Fair
Ray Fair
Yale
Disagree
5
Bio/Vote History
Finkelstein
Amy Finkelstein
MIT
Agree
1
Bio/Vote History
Goldberg
Pinelopi Goldberg
Yale
Disagree
9
Bio/Vote History
Goolsbee
Austan Goolsbee
Chicago
Strongly Disagree
10
Bio/Vote History
Just stop. Seriously.
Greenstone
Michael Greenstone
University of Chicago
Disagree
4
Bio/Vote History
Hall
Robert Hall
Stanford
Uncertain
3
Bio/Vote History
Some observers think that high inflation in 1974 was the result of elimination of earlier controls, which would suggest some control effects
Hart
Oliver Hart
Harvard
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
They could reduce inflation but the consequence would be shortages and rationing.
Holmström
Bengt Holmström
MIT
No Opinion
Bio/Vote History
Hoxby
Caroline Hoxby
Stanford
Disagree
10
Bio/Vote History
Hoynes
Hilary Hoynes
Berkeley
Disagree
8
Bio/Vote History
Judd
Kenneth Judd
Stanford
Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
Yes, it could reduce inflation over the short run - but only temporarily - just as the 1971 controls did. Too much money creation.
Kaplan
Steven Kaplan
Chicago Booth
Strongly Disagree
9
Bio/Vote History
Kashyap
Anil Kashyap
Chicago Booth
Disagree
7
Bio/Vote History
They would have to be draconian with fewer exceptions and even then the longer term effectiveness would be highly doubtful.
Klenow
Pete Klenow
Stanford
Disagree
5
Bio/Vote History
And they would distort price signals.
-see background information here
Levin
Jonathan Levin
Stanford
Disagree
4
Bio/Vote History
Maskin
Eric Maskin
Harvard
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
I imagine that price controls could restrain inflation---but that doesn't mean such controls are a good idea.
Nordhaus
William Nordhaus
Yale
Uncertain
9
Bio/Vote History
Perhaps could reduce inflation in short run as 1970s. Would only cause more shortages and a terrible idea.
Obstfeld
Maurice Obstfeld
Berkeley
Disagree
6
Bio/Vote History
Even if there were a negative effect on measured inflation (as in the early 1970s), shortages would raise shadow inflation.
Saez
Emmanuel Saez
Berkeley
Disagree
3
Bio/Vote History
Samuelson
Larry Samuelson
Yale
Disagree
8
Bio/Vote History
Price controls have had limited and temporary effects, while giving rise to lingering distortions.
Scheinkman
José Scheinkman
Columbia University
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Could lower measured inflation but would generate inefficiencies and cause even higher inflation when controls are lifted (see US 1974)
Schmalensee
Richard Schmalensee
MIT
Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
Over 12 months, probably, but with significant costs.
Shapiro
Carl Shapiro
Berkeley
Uncertain
4
Bio/Vote History
What does "successfully" mean? Price increases could be controlled to some degree but the underlying supply problems would be made worse.
Shimer
Robert Shimer
University of Chicago
Strongly Disagree
10
Bio/Vote History
Price controls could affect measured prices, but only by creating shortages, i.e. mismeasurement of true prices (inc. queues, waiting, etc)
Stock
James Stock
Harvard
Uncertain
4
Bio/Vote History
There might be some ephemeral success because of the way inflation is measured, but longer-run, price controls would be ineffective.
Thaler
Richard Thaler
Chicago Booth
Disagree
3
Bio/Vote History
Doubtful.
Udry
Christopher Udry
Northwestern
Disagree
5
Bio/Vote History