Leaders of the advanced economies of the G7 recently made what they described as a ‘historic commitment’ on taxation of multinational corporations. We invited both our European and US panels to express their views on some of the issues surrounding the global deal on corporate taxes: the impact of a global minimum rate on investment, profit-shifting and low-tax jurisdictions; whether a stable international tax system that includes a global minimum rate can be achieved; and a potential move from levying taxes based on where firms’ headquarters and production are located to where they make their sales.
We asked the experts whether they agreed or disagreed with the following statements, and, if so, how strongly and with what degree of confidence:
a) A global minimum corporate tax rate would limit the benefits to companies of shifting profits to low-tax jurisdictions without biasing where they invest.
b) A stable international tax system in which the major advanced economies set a minimum rate on corporate income is achievable.
c) A global corporate tax system that is based on the location of final consumers would be more efficient than one based on the location of corporate headquarters and production facilities.
Of our 48 European experts, 38 participated in this survey; of our 43 US experts, 37 participated – for a total of 75 expert reactions.
Countering profit-shifting to low-tax jurisdictions
On the first statement, a strong majority of panelists (94%) agrees that a global minimum corporate tax rate would limit the benefits of profit-shifting to low-tax jurisdictions without biasing where firms invest.
Weighted by each expert’s confidence in their response, 44% of the European panel strongly agree, 50% agree, 4% are uncertain, and 3% disagree (the totals don’t always sum to 100 because of rounding). Among the US panel (again weighted by each expert’s confidence in their response), 13% strongly agree, 82% agree, 5% are uncertain, and 0% disagree.
Overall, across both panels, 31% strongly agree, 63% agree, 4% are uncertain, and 2% disagree.
More nuances in the experts’ views come through in the short comments that they are able to include when they participate in the survey. Among those who agree with the statement, Jan Pieter Krahnen at Goethe University Frankfurt says: ‘This is exactly the argument of the proponents – and I think it is correct as a first order effect.’ Nicholas Bloom at Stanford explains: ‘Profit shifting is a curse for governments that want to properly tax capital. A global minimum tax is the best tool against this.’ His colleague Kenneth Judd adds: ‘Tax competition causes wasteful tax avoidance activities. This minimum also makes it easier for countries to bring down their rates.’
A number of panelists mention conditions of a global minimum achieving its objective. First, there’s what’s in the agreement. Franklin Allen at Imperial notes: ‘A lot will depend on the details of the agreement. If there are significant loopholes, the agreement is unlikely to work.’ Patrick Honohan at Trinity College Dublin suggests: ‘Provided definitions of taxable income are also harmonized.’ And Daron Acemoglu at MIT warns: ‘But the benefits from such a tax depend on the rate. Multilateral bargaining may lead to an excessively low rate, missing a huge opportunity.’
Next, there’s how widely the agreement is adopted, a challenge that OECD negotiators are currently facing with several developing countries and tax havens. Antoinette Schoar at MIT comments: ‘The big IF here is whether it will be possible to achieve uniform enforcement.’ Alan Auerbach at Berkeley adds: ‘It really depends on how widespread and uniform the adoption is.’ Pinelopi Goldberg at Yale states: ‘As long as the system is truly global, and international cooperation can be sustained.’ And Anil Kashyap at Chicago asks: ‘If adopted by all important economies and tax havens, but is that realistic?’
Of the panelists who say they are uncertain or disagree, several refer to the potential investment impact. Ricardo Reis at the London School of Economics (LSE) points out that: ‘All taxes (or almost all) bias investment decisions.’ Robert Shimer at Chicago adds: ‘But it will affect where they invest, reducing investment in currently-low-tax countries.’ And Pol Antras at Harvard exclaims: ‘It will certainly bias where they invest, but still seems like a splendid policy. We live in a second-best world!’
Caroline Hoxby at Stanford votes ‘no opinion’, but comments: ‘Such a proposal is pleasant to consider but is unrealistic in practice. Pie in the sky.’ And Pete Klenow at Stanford alerts us to a study of the unintended consequences of eliminating tax havens.
Setting a global minimum corporate tax rate
On the second statement about whether an international tax system with a global minimum rate on corporate income is achievable, there is considerably more uncertainty (with the US panel expressing more uncertainty than the European panel).
Weighted by each expert’s confidence in their response, 7% of the European panel strongly agree, 68% agree, 23% are uncertain, and 2% disagree. Among the US panel (again weighted by each expert’s confidence in their response), 6% strongly agree, 49% agree, 33% are uncertain, 7% disagree, and 5% strongly disagree.
Overall, across both panels, 7% strongly agree, 60% agree, 27% are uncertain, 4% disagree, and 2% strongly disagree.
Among the comments of panelists who agree, Austan Goolsbee at Chicago says: ‘The big economies are still hugely desirable and essential places to do business, not powerless small open economies in a race to the bottom.’ Pete Klenow adds: ‘Because of diminishing returns, not all capital will flee to the lowest tax location’, pointing us to his own research on relative prices and relative prosperity.
Others remark on the potential need for additional actions beyond the global minimum. Patrick Honohan notes: ‘But loopholes remain likely, thanks to effective corporate lobbying.’ Franklin Allen comments: ‘It may be achievable but if there are countries outside of the agreement that can become tax havens, then it may not work very well.’ Daron Acemoglu suggests: ‘Tax havens need to be regulated as well. There will be many more accounting tricks for tax evasion by MNEs. But feasible to close loopholes.’ And Jordi Gali at Barcelona calls for: ‘With heavy penalties for countries that do not abide.’
There are similar concerns among the panelists who say they are uncertain. Nicholas Bloom comments: ‘The incentives to deviate are too large to make this easy, or even achievable. Look at the troubles coordinating across US states or the EU.’ Jan Pieter Krahnen adds: ‘The devil is in the details – as we can already see from the responses from Ireland, the Bahamas, and the UK.’
Robert Hall at Stanford refers to research evidence on collective action: ‘The literature on the instability of cartels suggest there is a problem.’ Steven Kaplan at Chicago, who disagrees with the statement, adds: ‘Suspect it is very hard to get all relevant countries to agree/implement.’ But Karl Whelan at University College Dublin responds: ‘International economic policy co-operation is possible once there is recognition of common interests, e.g. Basel process for banking.’
Several panelists mention politics. Daniel Sturm at LSE suggests: ‘This is less a question about economics than political will or skill. Cooperation is the obvious best outcome for governments in this area.’ Christian Leuz at Chicago agrees: ‘More a political than an economic question. Answer largely depends on how much pressure major countries exert on tax havens. EU is case in point.’ And Richard Schmalensee at MIT notes simply: ‘I view this as an almost purely political question.’
Taxing firms based on sales location rather than production location
The third statement asks whether taxes based on where firms make their sales would be more efficient than taxes based on where their headquarters and production are located. While over half of panelists agree, more than a third express their uncertainty (including nearly half of the European panel).
Weighted by each expert’s confidence in their response, 19% of the European panel strongly agree, 32% agree, 47% are uncertain, and 2% disagree. Among the US panel (again weighted by each expert’s confidence in their response), 9% strongly agree, 63% agree, 27% are uncertain, and 0% disagree.
Overall, across both panels, 14% strongly agree, 47% agree, 38% are uncertain, and 1% disagree.
Among those who agree with the statement, Christopher Udry at Northwestern comments: ‘Not as easy to manipulate.’ Robert Hall says: ‘Consumption taxes make sense.’ And Kenneth Judd explains: ‘Taxes should not distort intermediate goods and production decisions, such as headquarters locations.’
Many of the panelists who say they are uncertain explain why they take that view. William Nordhaus at Yale says simply: ‘Very complicated and untested.’ Nicholas Bloom adds: ‘This is a complex issue that will vary by industry, country and company, so this is hard to answer.’ And Christian Leuz comments: ‘Many open questions and depends on details that are not spelled out in the question; such a system involves complex transfers across countries.’
A couple of panelists refer to specific issues of implementation. Franklin Allen states: ‘It depends how such a system is structured and which country receives the revenues.’ And Robert Shimer says: ‘Forcing small companies to pay taxes in any small country where people buy their products would be inefficient and anti-competitive.’
Others refer to tax theory. Caroline Hoxby suggests: ‘The location of consumers is an inferior system to the location of the owners of the capital.’ Karl Whelan remarks: ‘Effectively this would be a switch to a sales tax rather than a corporate income tax. I’m not sure this is necessarily more efficient.’ And Pol Antras comments: ‘Lacks theoretical foundation, and production-based approach is better in a first-best world. But it may improve upon current, flawed system.’
Daron Acemoglu also explains what underpins the uncertainty: ‘Headquarter location should be irrelevant. Uniform taxation is a good benchmark. Less clear whether based on consumption or production is better.’ And Daniel Sturm concludes: ‘The main point here should be distributional questions rather than narrow economic efficiency in the form of deadweight losses.’
All comments made by the experts are in the full survey results.
Romesh Vaitilingam
@econromesh
June 2021
Question A:
A global minimum corporate tax rate would limit the benefits to companies of shifting profits to low-tax jurisdictions without biasing where they invest.
Responses
Responses weighted by each expert's confidence
Question B:
A stable international tax system in which the major advanced economies collect a minimum rate on corporate income is achievable.
Responses
Responses weighted by each expert's confidence
Question C:
A global corporate tax system that is based on the location of final consumers would be more efficient than one based on the location of corporate headquarters and production facilities.
Responses
Responses weighted by each expert's confidence
Question A Participant Responses
Participant | University | Vote | Confidence | Bio/Vote History |
---|---|---|---|---|
Daron Acemoglu |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
But the benefits from such a tax depend on the rate. Multilateral bargaining may lead to an excessively low rate, missing a huge opportunity
|
||||
Joseph Altonji |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Alan Auerbach |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
It really depends on how widespread and uniform the adoption is.
|
||||
David Autor |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Katherine Baicker |
University of Chicago | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
Abhijit Banerjee |
MIT | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
Marianne Bertrand |
Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Markus Brunnermeier |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Raj Chetty |
Harvard | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
Judith Chevalier |
Yale | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
David Cutler |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Angus Deaton |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Darrell Duffie |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Aaron Edlin |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Barry Eichengreen |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Liran Einav |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Ray Fair |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Amy Finkelstein |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Pinelopi Goldberg |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
As long as the system is truly global, and international cooperation can be sustained.
|
||||
Austan Goolsbee |
Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
If combined with other efforts yes. As a stand alone, much more difficult
|
||||
Michael Greenstone |
University of Chicago | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
Robert Hall |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Oliver Hart |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Bengt Holmström |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Caroline Hoxby |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Such a proposal is pleasant to consider but is unrealistic in practice. Pie in the sky.
|
||||
Hilary Hoynes |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Kenneth Judd |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Tax competition causes wasteful tax avoidance activities. This minimum also makes it easier for countries to bring down their rates.
|
||||
Steven Kaplan |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Anil Kashyap |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
If adopted by all important economies and tax havens, but is that realistic?
|
||||
Pete Klenow |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Jonathan Levin |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Eric Maskin |
Harvard | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
William Nordhaus |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Maurice Obstfeld |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Emmanuel Saez |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Larry Samuelson |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
José Scheinkman |
Columbia University | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Richard Schmalensee |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
Reduced variation would limit benefits, but investment would be effected -- bias relative to what/
|
||||
Carl Shapiro |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Robert Shimer |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
But it will affect where they invest, reducing investment in currently-low-tax countries.
|
||||
James Stock |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Richard Thaler |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Christopher Udry |
Northwestern | Bio/Vote History | ||
It would depend on the details, of course
|
Question B Participant Responses
Participant | University | Vote | Confidence | Bio/Vote History |
---|---|---|---|---|
Daron Acemoglu |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
Tax havens need to be regulated as well. There will be many more accounting tricks for tax evasion by MNEs. But feasible to close loopholes.
|
||||
Joseph Altonji |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Alan Auerbach |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
David Autor |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Katherine Baicker |
University of Chicago | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
Abhijit Banerjee |
MIT | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
Marianne Bertrand |
Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Markus Brunnermeier |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Raj Chetty |
Harvard | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
Judith Chevalier |
Yale | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
David Cutler |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Angus Deaton |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Darrell Duffie |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Aaron Edlin |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Barry Eichengreen |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Liran Einav |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Ray Fair |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Amy Finkelstein |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Pinelopi Goldberg |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Austan Goolsbee |
Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
The big economies are still hugely desirable and essential places to do business not powerless small open economies in a race to the bottom.
|
||||
Michael Greenstone |
University of Chicago | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
Robert Hall |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
The literature on the instability of cartels suggest there is a problem
|
||||
Oliver Hart |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Bengt Holmström |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Caroline Hoxby |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Hilary Hoynes |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Kenneth Judd |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
I hope that it can be achieved, but one always has to be skeptical about the ability of political processes to result in rational decisions.
|
||||
Steven Kaplan |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
Suspect it is very hard to get all relevant countries to agree / implement.
|
||||
Anil Kashyap |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
Ireland?
|
||||
Pete Klenow |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Because of diminishing returns, not all capital will flee to the lowest tax location.
-see background information here |
||||
Jonathan Levin |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Eric Maskin |
Harvard | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
William Nordhaus |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Maurice Obstfeld |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Emmanuel Saez |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Larry Samuelson |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
José Scheinkman |
Columbia University | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Richard Schmalensee |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
I view this as an almost purely political question.
|
||||
Carl Shapiro |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Robert Shimer |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
Hard to close all loopholes
|
||||
James Stock |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Richard Thaler |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
Crystal ball is broken
|
||||
Christopher Udry |
Northwestern | Bio/Vote History | ||
I'm an optimist.
|
Question C Participant Responses
Participant | University | Vote | Confidence | Bio/Vote History |
---|---|---|---|---|
Daron Acemoglu |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
Headquarter location should be irrelevant. Uniform taxation is a good benchmark. Less clear whether based on cons. or production is better.
|
||||
Joseph Altonji |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Alan Auerbach |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
David Autor |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Katherine Baicker |
University of Chicago | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
Abhijit Banerjee |
MIT | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
Marianne Bertrand |
Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Markus Brunnermeier |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Raj Chetty |
Harvard | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
Judith Chevalier |
Yale | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
David Cutler |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Angus Deaton |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Darrell Duffie |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Aaron Edlin |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Barry Eichengreen |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Liran Einav |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Ray Fair |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Amy Finkelstein |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Pinelopi Goldberg |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Austan Goolsbee |
Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
Sometimes the easiest thing to do is the quickest way to piss people off and that’s why they didn’t do it in the first place.
|
||||
Michael Greenstone |
University of Chicago | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
Robert Hall |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Consumption taxes make sense
|
||||
Oliver Hart |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Bengt Holmström |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Caroline Hoxby |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
The location of consumers is an inferior system to the location of the owners of the capital.
|
||||
Hilary Hoynes |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Kenneth Judd |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Taxes should not distort intermediate goods and production decisions, such as headquarters locations.
|
||||
Steven Kaplan |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Anil Kashyap |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Pete Klenow |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Jonathan Levin |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Eric Maskin |
Harvard | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
William Nordhaus |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
Very complicated and untested
|
||||
Maurice Obstfeld |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Emmanuel Saez |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Larry Samuelson |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
José Scheinkman |
Columbia University | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Richard Schmalensee |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Carl Shapiro |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Robert Shimer |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
Forcing small companies to pay taxes in any small country where people buy their products would be inefficient and anticompetitive
|
||||
James Stock |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Richard Thaler |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
Just depends on what is hardest to game. I don't know the answer to that.
|
||||
Christopher Udry |
Northwestern | Bio/Vote History | ||
Not as easy to manipulate
|