Germany’s Debt Brake

Question A:

A constitutional rule that limits the size of budget deficits that governments can run as a share of GDP is an effective way to impose discipline on a country’s public finances.

Responses weighted by each expert's confidence

Question B:

Germany’s debt brake is a substantial constraint on vital public investment in physical/digital infrastructure and the green transition.

Responses weighted by each expert's confidence

Question A Participant Responses

Participant University Vote Confidence Bio/Vote History
Allen
Franklin Allen
Imperial College London
Uncertain
5
Bio/Vote History
It's a difficult question with arguments both ways. In favor, it does seem to have the effect of reducing expenditure in Switzerland although it's unclear what the counterfactual is there. In Germany, it seems to have lead to poor expenditure decisions, particularly investment.
Antras
Pol Antras
Harvard
Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
But that’s only one of the objectives governments should have.
Blanchard
Olivier Blanchard
Peterson Institute
Agree
9
Bio/Vote History
If the rule is espected, it does indeed impose fiscal discipline. At the potential cost of the potential loss of fiscal policy as a tool for macro stabilisation.
Bloom
Nicholas Bloom
Stanford
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Blundell
Richard William Blundell
University College London Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Botticini
Maristella Botticini
Bocconi
Uncertain
6
Bio/Vote History
Bénassy-Quéré
Agnès Bénassy-Quéré
Paris School of Economics
Strongly Agree
10
Bio/Vote History
Carletti
Elena Carletti
Bocconi
Uncertain
7
Bio/Vote History
Danthine
Jean-Pierre Danthine
Paris School of Economics
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
De Grauwe
Paul De Grauwe
LSE
Disagree
7
Bio/Vote History
Eeckhout
Jan Eeckhout
UPF Barcelona
Uncertain
6
Bio/Vote History
The limit will be renegotiated in an emergency (war, natural disaster,...). And when it is binding, the success/failure depends crucially on other institutional details, such as the ability of small groups to hold up the workings of the government and threats to shut down
Fehr
Ernst Fehr
Universität Zurich Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Freixas
Xavier Freixas
Barcelona GSE
Strongly Agree
10
Bio/Vote History
Fuchs-Schündeln
Nicola Fuchs-Schündeln
Goethe-Universität Frankfurt
Agree
9
Bio/Vote History
It is definitely effective (at least to some degree), but the question is whether it is the best way to achieve discipline.
Galí
Jordi Galí
Barcelona GSE
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Garicano
Luis Garicano
LSE
Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
Gorodnichenko
Yuriy Gorodnichenko
Berkeley
Strongly Disagree
9
Bio/Vote History
Griffith
Rachel Griffith
University of Manchester
No Opinion
Bio/Vote History
Guerrieri
Veronica Guerrieri
Chicago Booth Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Guiso
Luigi Guiso
Einaudi Institute for Economics and Finance
Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
Guriev
Sergei Guriev
Sciences Po
Uncertain
5
Bio/Vote History
Honohan
Patrick Honohan
Trinity College Dublin
Disagree
8
Bio/Vote History
Inflexible constitutional rules have drawbacks that are worse than those associated with leaving thee matters to government.
Javorcik
Beata Javorcik
University of Oxford
Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
Krahnen
Jan Pieter Krahnen
Goethe University Frankfurt
Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
The constitutional debt brake certainly imposes discipline, and it imposes pressure on non-investment spending. It does, by the way, not necessarily limit investment iff infrastructure investment is financed via private co-financing - typically requiring user fees to be imposed.
Kőszegi
Botond Kőszegi
Central European University
Agree
1
Bio/Vote History
La Ferrara
Eliana La Ferrara
Harvard Kennedy Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Leuz
Christian Leuz
Chicago Booth
Agree
3
Bio/Vote History
Mayer
Thierry Mayer
Sciences-Po
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Meghir
Costas Meghir
Yale
Disagree
9
Bio/Vote History
Pagano
Marco Pagano
Università di Napoli Federico II
Disagree
7
Bio/Vote History
As the German case itself shows, it can be circumvented. Rightly so, because it is a stupid rule.
Pastor
Lubos Pastor
Chicago Booth
Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
Effective, yes. Desirable? Unclear.
Persson
Torsten Persson
Stockholm University Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Pissarides
Christopher Pissarides
London School of Economics and Political Science Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Portes
Richard Portes
London Business School
Strongly Disagree
9
Bio/Vote History
It is ineffective insofar as it motivates various efforts to avoid it.
Prendergast
Canice Prendergast
Chicago Booth
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Propper
Carol Propper
Imperial College London Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Rasul
Imran Rasul
University College London Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Reichlin
Lucrezia Reichlin
London Business School
Disagree
9
Bio/Vote History
Reis
Ricardo Reis
London School of Economics
Disagree
7
Bio/Vote History
One number for the deficit will rarely be optimal. And, within the set of sub-optimal second-best rules, there seem to be better alternatives.
Repullo
Rafael Repullo
CEMFI
Uncertain
6
Bio/Vote History
Rey
Hélène Rey
London Business School Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Schoar
Antoinette Schoar
MIT
Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
Storesletten
Kjetil Storesletten
University of Minnesota
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Sturm
Daniel Sturm
London School of Economics
Agree
4
Bio/Vote History
Tenreyro
Silvana Tenreyro
LSE
Agree
2
Bio/Vote History
Van Reenen
John Van Reenen
LSE
Strongly Disagree
8
Bio/Vote History
(i) Need to take into account asset side as well as debt (so net worth target important); (ii) overly-constrains government responses to negative shocks
-see background information here
Van der Ploeg
Rick Van der Ploeg
Oxford
Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
Due to common pool problem and sometimes weak ministers of finance, it is helpful to have such a rule provided it allows leeway for productive government investments ("golden rule").
Vickers
John Vickers
Oxford
Uncertain
4
Bio/Vote History
Effective at what? At pure discipline, probably yes. In economic terms not unless well designed with respect to cyclical and investment issues.
Voth
Hans-Joachim Voth
University of Zurich
Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
"effective" = yes. Wise? More doubtful.
Whelan
Karl Whelan
University College Dublin
Strongly Disagree
10
Bio/Vote History
I don't think this kind of rule is necessarily effective. It encourages accounting gimmicks whereby certain types of spending appears "off balance sheet". It also has now basis in economy theory as a useful policy rule.
Wyplosz
Charles Wyplosz
The Graduate Institute Geneva
Strongly Agree
10
Bio/Vote History
Most governments succumb to temptation unless strongly constrained. This is a straightforward implication of time inconsistency.

Question B Participant Responses

Participant University Vote Confidence Bio/Vote History
Allen
Franklin Allen
Imperial College London
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
This seems to be the case. They are falling behind in these critical areas because of these constraints.
Antras
Pol Antras
Harvard
Uncertain
1
Bio/Vote History
Blanchard
Olivier Blanchard
Peterson Institute
Strongly Agree
9
Bio/Vote History
There is a trade off between debt reduction and public investment, be it defense or green spending. The debt brake may well force choosing the wrong point on the trade off curve.
Bloom
Nicholas Bloom
Stanford
Uncertain
4
Bio/Vote History
Blundell
Richard William Blundell
University College London Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Botticini
Maristella Botticini
Bocconi
Uncertain
6
Bio/Vote History
Bénassy-Quéré
Agnès Bénassy-Quéré
Paris School of Economics
Strongly Agree
10
Bio/Vote History
Carletti
Elena Carletti
Bocconi
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Danthine
Jean-Pierre Danthine
Paris School of Economics
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
De Grauwe
Paul De Grauwe
LSE
Strongly Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
Eeckhout
Jan Eeckhout
UPF Barcelona
Uncertain
6
Bio/Vote History
Fehr
Ernst Fehr
Universität Zurich Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Freixas
Xavier Freixas
Barcelona GSE
Strongly Agree
10
Bio/Vote History
Fuchs-Schündeln
Nicola Fuchs-Schündeln
Goethe-Universität Frankfurt
Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
Galí
Jordi Galí
Barcelona GSE
No Opinion
Bio/Vote History
Garicano
Luis Garicano
LSE
Disagree
6
Bio/Vote History
Investments do not need to be finances with debt
Gorodnichenko
Yuriy Gorodnichenko
Berkeley
Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
Griffith
Rachel Griffith
University of Manchester
No Opinion
Bio/Vote History
Guerrieri
Veronica Guerrieri
Chicago Booth Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Guiso
Luigi Guiso
Einaudi Institute for Economics and Finance
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Guriev
Sergei Guriev
Sciences Po
Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
Honohan
Patrick Honohan
Trinity College Dublin
Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
Javorcik
Beata Javorcik
University of Oxford
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Krahnen
Jan Pieter Krahnen
Goethe University Frankfurt
Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
Despite my earlier argument, namely that the debt brake can be "loosened" via PPP programs, the political reality in Germany clearly has little tolerance for user fees, and therefore the debt brake also cuts into public spending, moistly on investment - unfortunately.
Kőszegi
Botond Kőszegi
Central European University
Agree
3
Bio/Vote History
La Ferrara
Eliana La Ferrara
Harvard Kennedy Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Leuz
Christian Leuz
Chicago Booth
Agree
3
Bio/Vote History
It is substantial constraint for two reasons. For one, large other spending. The purpose of debt brake is to force politicians to make tradeoffs. Second, the brake makes no distinction between consumption and investment. It could make sense to treat (some) investment differently.
Mayer
Thierry Mayer
Sciences-Po
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Meghir
Costas Meghir
Yale
Agree
9
Bio/Vote History
Pagano
Marco Pagano
Università di Napoli Federico II
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Pastor
Lubos Pastor
Chicago Booth
Strongly Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
Persson
Torsten Persson
Stockholm University Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Pissarides
Christopher Pissarides
London School of Economics and Political Science Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Portes
Richard Portes
London Business School
Strongly Agree
10
Bio/Vote History
Prendergast
Canice Prendergast
Chicago Booth
Uncertain
4
Bio/Vote History
Propper
Carol Propper
Imperial College London Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Rasul
Imran Rasul
University College London Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Reichlin
Lucrezia Reichlin
London Business School
Agree
9
Bio/Vote History
Reis
Ricardo Reis
London School of Economics
No Opinion
Bio/Vote History
Repullo
Rafael Repullo
CEMFI
Disagree
6
Bio/Vote History
Rey
Hélène Rey
London Business School Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Schoar
Antoinette Schoar
MIT
Uncertain
6
Bio/Vote History
Storesletten
Kjetil Storesletten
University of Minnesota
Disagree
7
Bio/Vote History
Sturm
Daniel Sturm
London School of Economics
Uncertain
5
Bio/Vote History
Tenreyro
Silvana Tenreyro
LSE
Agree
2
Bio/Vote History
Van Reenen
John Van Reenen
LSE
Strongly Agree
10
Bio/Vote History
Van der Ploeg
Rick Van der Ploeg
Oxford
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
A debt brake indeed carries the danger that it crowd out productive public investments (as has been the case with the Maastricht criteria).
Vickers
John Vickers
Oxford
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Especially after November’s Constitutional Court ruling
Voth
Hans-Joachim Voth
University of Zurich
Strongly Disagree
8
Bio/Vote History
Low investment reflect political economy considerations; there will never be enough revenue to repair roads and schools and invest in digital infrastructure under the current government. All funds will be diverted to green + social spending.
Whelan
Karl Whelan
University College Dublin
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Climate investment has to be financed whether via debt or taxes. Just because Germany can't borrow more to finance it, doesn't mean it can't be done. But Germany currently has a sustainable debt level, so debt is one way it could be financed and this places restrictions on that.
Wyplosz
Charles Wyplosz
The Graduate Institute Geneva
Strongly Disagree
10
Bio/Vote History
If public investment is really vital, it is possible to cut other spending or raise taxes. The budget constraint is not an option.