Question A:
Giving the President more direct influence over monetary policy would lead to substantially worse monetary policy decisions.
Responses
Responses weighted by each expert's confidence
Question B:
Imposing tariffs results in a substantial portion of the tariffs being borne by consumers of the country that enacts the tariffs, through price increases.
Responses
Responses weighted by each expert's confidence
Question C:
There is little empirical evidence that price gouging is causing high grocery prices.
Responses
Responses weighted by each expert's confidence
Question D:
Widespread use of price controls creates substantial economic distortions.
Responses
Responses weighted by each expert's confidence
Question A Participant Responses
Participant | University | Vote | Confidence | Bio/Vote History |
---|---|---|---|---|
Daron Acemoglu |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
Just look at Turkish monetary policy over the last decade as proof. Yet I am no longer convinced that the current independent central banker model is ideal either, because it has created a bias towards propping up financial asset values. We may need to consider alternatives.
|
||||
Mark Aguiar |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Joseph Altonji |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Alan Auerbach |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
David Autor |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Abhijit Banerjee |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Dirk Bergemann |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Marianne Bertrand |
Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Markus Brunnermeier |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Judith Chevalier |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
David Cutler |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Darrell Duffie |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Is this a trick question? Only a weird person would advocate this approach. Central banks are independent in order to insulate monetary policy from conflicts of interest related to near-term election results.
|
||||
Aaron Edlin |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Barry Eichengreen |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Liran Einav |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Ray Fair |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Edward Glaeser |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Pinelopi Goldberg |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Michael Greenstone |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Oliver Hart |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Bengt Holmström |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Caroline Hoxby |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Hilary Hoynes |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Erik Hurst |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Kenneth Judd |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
NOTE: Respondent meant to answer "Strongly Agree" to this question.
Look at history. Nixon appointed Burns to the Fed who then, under pressure from Nixon, set off double digit money creation. Carter appointed Volcker and told him to combat inflation. Volcker raised interest rates in 1980, which surely harmed Carter's reelection campaign.
|
||||
Steven Kaplan |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Anil Kashyap |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
Pete Klenow |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Jonathan Levin |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Eric Maskin |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
The folly of putting the money supply in political hands has been demonstrated many times in the last hundred years.
|
||||
William Nordhaus |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Maurice Obstfeld |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Parag Pathak |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Larry Samuelson |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
The key to the Fed's design, and it success, is that it is insulated from political pressures.
|
||||
José Scheinkman |
Columbia University | Bio/Vote History | ||
Monetary history of Latin America over the last 100 years provides strong evidence for the high cost of direct influence of the executive branch over monetary policy
-see background information here |
||||
Richard Schmalensee |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Fiona Scott Morton |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Carl Shapiro |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Robert Shimer |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
Independent central banks are largely responsible for the substantial decline in inflation since 1980 (notwithstanding the last four years)
|
||||
James Stock |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Nancy Stokey |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Chad Syverson |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
There is plenty of empirical evidence and a history of hard lessons learned demonstrating that some independence of the monetary authority from the political process--especially in the short term--is beneficial.
|
||||
Richard Thaler |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Christopher Udry |
Northwestern | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
Question B Participant Responses
Participant | University | Vote | Confidence | Bio/Vote History |
---|---|---|---|---|
Daron Acemoglu |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
Likely true, but depends on demand and supply elasticities as well as whether tariffs affect markups. Also depends on whether tariffs can change production structure and impact efficiency in the medium run, à la infant industry arguments. The evidence is still not fully clear.
|
||||
Mark Aguiar |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Joseph Altonji |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Alan Auerbach |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
David Autor |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Abhijit Banerjee |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Dirk Bergemann |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
The effect of the tariff depends on the condition of the supply. If the products are offered competitively by many countries, then the effect on domestic consumer is likely to be small.
|
||||
Marianne Bertrand |
Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Markus Brunnermeier |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Judith Chevalier |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
David Cutler |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Darrell Duffie |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
At least two channels are at play: (1) lack of perfect substitutability with suitable domestic products, and (2) increased market power for domestic producers.
|
||||
Aaron Edlin |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Barry Eichengreen |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Liran Einav |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Ray Fair |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Edward Glaeser |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Pinelopi Goldberg |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
Usually this is the case. Unless the exporter "eats" the tariffs. Recent experience from the US tariffs on Chinese imports suggests that the tariff incidence was on US importers.
-see background information here |
||||
Michael Greenstone |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Oliver Hart |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Bengt Holmström |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
But depends on target
|
||||
Caroline Hoxby |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Hilary Hoynes |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Erik Hurst |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Kenneth Judd |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
When costs go up, firms will raise prices to their customers. Need I say more?
|
||||
Steven Kaplan |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Anil Kashyap |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Pete Klenow |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Jonathan Levin |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Eric Maskin |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
The direct effect of the tariff is certainly to reduce consumers' welfare. Still, it is conceivable that a sufficiently small tariff could lead to a Pareto improvement in the tariff-imposing country if there were suitable redistribution.
|
||||
William Nordhaus |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Maurice Obstfeld |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Parag Pathak |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Larry Samuelson |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
José Scheinkman |
Columbia University | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Richard Schmalensee |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
Not all tariffs, not all countries, but in the present context, yes.
|
||||
Fiona Scott Morton |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Carl Shapiro |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Robert Shimer |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
A substantial portion is also borne by exporting firms (and their workers) through exchange rate adjustment.
|
||||
James Stock |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Nancy Stokey |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Chad Syverson |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
Theory says importer pays an amount that depends on relative supply and demand elasticities. Only in a polar case is importer's share zero. Empirical evidence (one example below) says importer typically bears a lot. Plus there are competitive effects on domestic prices too.
-see background information here |
||||
Richard Thaler |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Christopher Udry |
Northwestern | Bio/Vote History | ||
obviously this depends on the elasticities, but this is most often exactly what happens.
|
Question C Participant Responses
Participant | University | Vote | Confidence | Bio/Vote History |
---|---|---|---|---|
Daron Acemoglu |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
There is evidence that markups have increased in a number of sectors, though this evidence is still not fully conclusive. More importantly for this question, this increase has been slow and secular, so not what could contribute to a sudden surge to inflation.
|
||||
Mark Aguiar |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Joseph Altonji |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Alan Auerbach |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
David Autor |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Abhijit Banerjee |
MIT | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
Dirk Bergemann |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Marianne Bertrand |
Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Markus Brunnermeier |
Princeton | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
Judith Chevalier |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
I think "price gouging" is a term that does not have a real meaning to economists? If it means "market power", yes in some segments (poultry) and no in others (retail).
|
||||
David Cutler |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Darrell Duffie |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Aaron Edlin |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Barry Eichengreen |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Liran Einav |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Ray Fair |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Edward Glaeser |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Pinelopi Goldberg |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Michael Greenstone |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Oliver Hart |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Bengt Holmström |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Caroline Hoxby |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Hilary Hoynes |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Erik Hurst |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Kenneth Judd |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Steven Kaplan |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Anil Kashyap |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Pete Klenow |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Jonathan Levin |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Eric Maskin |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
William Nordhaus |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
Some rhetorical question here in def of price gouging.
|
||||
Maurice Obstfeld |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Parag Pathak |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Larry Samuelson |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
Increasing grocery prices are a particularly visible manifestation of inflation, which has many causes (such as a lack of fiscal discipline) much more important than price gouging.
|
||||
José Scheinkman |
Columbia University | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Richard Schmalensee |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Fiona Scott Morton |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
The lack of evidence does not mean the behavior wasn't present because it is difficult to study. The pandemic shortages changed expectations, allowing firms to raise prices for multiple reasons.
|
||||
Carl Shapiro |
Berkeley | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
Robert Shimer |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
James Stock |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Nancy Stokey |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Chad Syverson |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
Don't know price gouging's precise definition, so I will answer "uncertain." (Handwaving plagues the current discussion of grocery prices.) If it is standing in for some shifting competitive equilibrium markup, then paper linked below is convincing that isn't happening.
-see background information here |
||||
Richard Thaler |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
"price gouging" (usually defined as a big increase in price in a crisis like a hurricane) is against the law in many states, and most big firms smartly do the opposite, sell cheap (and give away water) to burnish long-term reputation. Irrelevant to food inflation.
|
||||
Christopher Udry |
Northwestern | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
Question D Participant Responses
Participant | University | Vote | Confidence | Bio/Vote History |
---|---|---|---|---|
Daron Acemoglu |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
The devil may be in the detail. In sectors with very high markups, reasonably well designed price controls may create fewer distortions. On the whole, however, price controls could easily get out of hand and cause damage.
|
||||
Mark Aguiar |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Joseph Altonji |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Alan Auerbach |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
David Autor |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
But sometimes their absence also enables other distortions, such as in markets for patented pharmaceuticals, or the extreme fees charged by banks and credit card companies to exploit the vulnerabilities of low income consumers
|
||||
Abhijit Banerjee |
MIT | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
Dirk Bergemann |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Marianne Bertrand |
Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Markus Brunnermeier |
Princeton | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
Judith Chevalier |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
David Cutler |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Darrell Duffie |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Widespread price constraints stifle supply and allocative efficiency.
|
||||
Aaron Edlin |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Barry Eichengreen |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Liran Einav |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Ray Fair |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Edward Glaeser |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
Pinelopi Goldberg |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Michael Greenstone |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Oliver Hart |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Bengt Holmström |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Caroline Hoxby |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Hilary Hoynes |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Erik Hurst |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Kenneth Judd |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Steven Kaplan |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Anil Kashyap |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Pete Klenow |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Jonathan Levin |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Eric Maskin |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
William Nordhaus |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Maurice Obstfeld |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Parag Pathak |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Larry Samuelson |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
José Scheinkman |
Columbia University | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Richard Schmalensee |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Fiona Scott Morton |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Carl Shapiro |
Berkeley | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
Robert Shimer |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
James Stock |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Nancy Stokey |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Chad Syverson |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
Widespread price controls have been tried in many settings and end up being, euphemistically, a huge mess. Pairing them with quantity restrictions can limit some types of damage but create others.
|
||||
Richard Thaler |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Christopher Udry |
Northwestern | Bio/Vote History | ||
|