With Congress working on a $1.9 trillion Covid-19 relief package, potentially including an additional $1,400 in direct payments to individuals, we invited our US panel to express their views on the proposals. We asked the experts whether they agree or disagree with the following statements, and, if so, how strongly and with what degree of confidence:
(a) Until mass vaccination is achieved, any additional government spending going directly to households should focus on keeping low-income individuals and families safe and healthy rather than on boosting current economic activity.
(b) If the goal is to boost current economic activity, targeting checks at households making less than $75,000 per year would be more cost-effective than providing checks to higher income households as well.
Relief for low-income households
Of our 43 US experts, 42 participated in this survey. On the first statement about whether additional spending should be focused more on relief than stimulus while there remains a considerable threat to public health from economic activity, over 80% agree. Weighted by each expert’s confidence in their response, 18% of the US panel strongly agree, 64% agree, 12% are uncertain, and 6% disagree.
The experts are able to include short comments in their responses, and among those who agree or strongly agree with the statement, Larry Samuelson at Yale says: ‘The recession is a public health emergency, and stimulus without first addressing the health issues can be ineffective or counterproductive.’ Kenneth Judd at Stanford adds: ‘”Stimulus” should not be the focus. Much of what is proposed is economic relief to those who are facing economic ruin.’
A couple of experts explain their interpretation of the statement. Carl Shapiro at Berkeley notes: ‘Defining “safe and healthy: in a broad manner to include economic security.’ Daron Acemoglu at MIT states: ‘Interpreting “safe and healthy” as enough money to prevent poverty for low-income households. Also aid for state and local governments is important.
Jonathan Levin at Stanford adds a further consideration: ‘Agree on focus. Investment in testing and accelerating vaccination also welcome.’ Similarly, Christopher Udry at Northwestern comments: ‘Transfers to low-income families are needed for safety and health. Vaccines, testing and tracing more important than spending for stimulus.’
Additional caveats include one from Robert Shimer at Chicago, who mentions: ‘The only caveat is that disease prevalence may fall substantially before mass vaccination is achieved.’ James Stock at Harvard observes: ‘Caveat: if those vaccinated (older, wealthier) start feeling safe we might start to see services demand return early than full vaccination.’ Robert Hall at Stanford adds: ‘Economic activity is depressed mainly by supply restrictions’; and Pete Klenow at Stanford alerts us to their joint paper with Charles Jones on trading off consumption and Covid-19 deaths.
Among experts who say they are uncertain: Joseph Altonji at Yale comments: ‘Spending should focus both on health, which will help the economy, and on the economy, prioritizing those in need.’ Steven Kaplan at Chicago says: ‘Hard to have confidence in anything with regard to the virus. Ideally want to have economic and school activity while keeping people safe.’ Anil Kashyap at Chicago notes: ‘Propping up zombie firms and giving people checks that just get saved is not good. Some other support could still be useful. Details matter.’ And Maurice Obstfeld at Berkeley concludes: ‘Health/safety for low-income a priority, but there likely remains some negative output gap.’
Among the minority who disagree that making relief a priority over stimulus, David Cutler at Harvard says: ‘These aren’t in conflict now.’ David Autor at MIT adds: ‘Infection rates and deaths are falling and vaccination rollout is accelerating. It’s time to start recovery. Biden won’t get two at-bats.’
Targeting checks
The second statement focuses on whether the proposed ‘stimulus checks’ should be targeted at households making less than $75,000 per year – and here there is a strong majority of over 90% in agreement. Again weighted by each expert’s confidence in their response, 37% strongly agree, 57% agree, 6% are uncertain, and 0% disagree.
Among those who say they strongly agree, David Autor notes: ‘Evidence is that households with higher incomes simply put the money in the bank. We don’t need government handouts to spur personal savings.’ Richard Schmalensee at MIT agrees: ‘High-income households are more likely to save the money.’ And Raj Chetty at Harvard points to analysis he and colleagues recently did of the effects of the January 2021 stimulus payments on consumer spending.
Others refer to the different propensities to consume from additional income. Robert Shimer responds: ‘Wealthier households have been building up their savings and would likely do the same with any new “stimulus” checks.’ Aaron Edlin at Berkeley notes: ‘We already have a pile of savings from the well off. Targeting money to those who spend is most likely to increase spending.’ And Darrell Duffie at Stanford explains: ‘I’m assuming that the higher marginal propensity to consume of lower income earners is the dominant factor in making this comparison.’
Focusing on individuals and families who need relief, Larry Samuelson states: ‘The brunt of the pandemic has fallen on those at the bottom of the scale, and relief is most needed and will be most effective there.’ Jonathan Levin comments: ‘Yes, but might think less in terms of stimulus multiplier and more about aiding at-risk families.’ And Markus Brunnermeier at Princeton adds: ‘Targeting unemployed or households who suffered losses due to COVID shock would be even more desirable.’
Further caveats include this from Caroline Hoxby at Stanford: ‘I agree with the question as asked, but this is also a crude way of targeting compared to what could be attained by using available data.’ And Carl Shapiro argues: ‘This seems very clear, but there is nothing magic about using $75,000 as the upper limit.’
Finally, among the experts who agree, William Nordhaus at Yale concludes: ‘Both on equity and efficiency grounds, this is appropriate approach.’ And Anil Kashyap refers to wider concerns about macroeconomic policy: ‘We will have to pay off the debt and there are lots of pressing other needs. So conserving fiscal space is desirable.’
Two experts who say they are uncertain point to the same issue. Hilary Hoynes at Berkeley notes: ‘The problem is that the phase out is based on *2019* income – many with higher incomes in 2019 could be in financial stress now.’ Judith Chevalier at Yale adds: ‘I would be more inclined to agree if we had a mechanism to target based on actual current circumstances rather than 2019 tax income.’
All comments made by the experts are in the full survey results.
Romesh Vaitilingam
@econromesh
February 2021
Question A:
Until mass vaccination is achieved, any additional government spending going directly to households should focus on keeping low-income individuals and families safe and healthy rather than on boosting current economic activity.
Responses
Responses weighted by each expert's confidence
Question B:
If the goal is to boost current economic activity, targeting checks at households making less than $75,000 per year would be more cost-effective than providing checks to higher income households as well.
Responses
Responses weighted by each expert's confidence
Question A Participant Responses
Participant | University | Vote | Confidence | Bio/Vote History |
---|---|---|---|---|
Daron Acemoglu |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
Interpreting "safe and healthy" as enough money to prevent poverty for low income households. Also aid for state and local govs is important
|
||||
Joseph Altonji |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
Wording is tricky. Spending should focus both on health, which will help the economy, and on the economy, prioritizing those in need.
|
||||
Alan Auerbach |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
David Autor |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
Infection rates + deaths are falling and vaccination rollout is accelerating. It's time to start recovery. Biden won't get two at-bats
|
||||
Katherine Baicker |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Abhijit Banerjee |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Marianne Bertrand |
Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Markus Brunnermeier |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Raj Chetty |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Judith Chevalier |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
Of course, resources designed to open school safely, etc. also are helpful to the economy.
|
||||
David Cutler |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
These aren't in conflict now.
|
||||
Angus Deaton |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Darrell Duffie |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
I had difficulty interpreting the phrase "rather than," but the prioritization of safety and health seems natural.
|
||||
Aaron Edlin |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
My answer might change if the economy heads too far south.
|
||||
Barry Eichengreen |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Liran Einav |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Ray Fair |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Amy Finkelstein |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Pinelopi Goldberg |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Austan Goolsbee |
Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
Yee
|
||||
Michael Greenstone |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Robert Hall |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Economic activity is depressed mainly by supply restrictions
|
||||
Oliver Hart |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Bengt Holmström |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Caroline Hoxby |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Hilary Hoynes |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
key here is how to define 'low income" - I say yes for those in need.
|
||||
Kenneth Judd |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
"Stimulus" should not be the focus. Much of what is proposed is economic relief to those who are facing economic ruin.
|
||||
Steven Kaplan |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
Hard to have confidence in anything with regard to the virus. Ideally want to have economic and school activity while keeping people safe.
|
||||
Anil Kashyap |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
Propping up zombie firms and giving people checks that just get saved is not good. Some other support could still be useful. Details matter
|
||||
Pete Klenow |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Jonathan Levin |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Agree on focus. Investment in testing and accelerating vaccination also welcome.
|
||||
Eric Maskin |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
William Nordhaus |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
False dichotomy.
|
||||
Maurice Obstfeld |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
Health/safety for low-income a priority, but there likely remains some negative output gap.
|
||||
Emmanuel Saez |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Larry Samuelson |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
The recession is a public health emergency, and stimulus without first addressing the health issues can be ineffective or counterproductive.
|
||||
José Scheinkman |
Columbia University | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
Richard Schmalensee |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
Will also boost activity, since mpc is high for low-income households.
|
||||
Carl Shapiro |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
Defining "safe and healthy" in a broad manner to include economic security.
|
||||
Robert Shimer |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
The only caveat is that disease prevalence may fall substantially before mass vaccination is achieved.
|
||||
James Stock |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
Caveat: if those vaccinated (older, wealthier) start feeling safe we might start to see services demand return early than full vaccination.
|
||||
Richard Thaler |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Christopher Udry |
Northwestern | Bio/Vote History | ||
Transfers to low income families are needed for safety and health. Vaccines, testing and tracing more important than spending for stimulus.
|
Question B Participant Responses
Participant | University | Vote | Confidence | Bio/Vote History |
---|---|---|---|---|
Daron Acemoglu |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Joseph Altonji |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Alan Auerbach |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
David Autor |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
Evidence is that HH's with higher incomes simply put the money in the bank. We don't need government handouts to spur personal savings.
|
||||
Katherine Baicker |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Abhijit Banerjee |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Marianne Bertrand |
Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Markus Brunnermeier |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
targeting unemployed or households who suffered losses due to COVID shock would be even more desirable
|
||||
Raj Chetty |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
Judith Chevalier |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
I would be more inclined to agree if we had a mechanism to target based on actual current circumstances rather than 2019 tax income.
|
||||
David Cutler |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Angus Deaton |
Princeton | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Darrell Duffie |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
I'm assuming that the higher marginal propensity to consume of lower income earners is the dominant factor in making this comparison.
|
||||
Aaron Edlin |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
We already have a pile of savings from the well off. Targeting money to those who spend is most likely to increase spending.
|
||||
Barry Eichengreen |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Liran Einav |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Ray Fair |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Amy Finkelstein |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Pinelopi Goldberg |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Austan Goolsbee |
Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Michael Greenstone |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Robert Hall |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Subsidies to higher income households don't raise spending significantly, but go into saving.
|
||||
Oliver Hart |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Bengt Holmström |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Caroline Hoxby |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
I agree w the question as asked, but this is also a crude way of targeting compared to what could be attained by using available data.
|
||||
Hilary Hoynes |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
The problem is that the phase out is based on *2019* income - many with higher incomes in 2019 could be in financial stress now.
|
||||
Kenneth Judd |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
This is always true for recession policies. Economists have failed to develop policies that are properly targeted. Why?
|
||||
Steven Kaplan |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Anil Kashyap |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
we will have to pay off the debt and there are lots of pressing other needs. so conserving fiscal space is desirable
|
||||
Pete Klenow |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Jonathan Levin |
Stanford | Bio/Vote History | ||
Yes, but might think less in terms of stimulus multiplier and more about aiding at-risk families
|
||||
Eric Maskin |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
William Nordhaus |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
Both on equity and efficiency grounds, this is appropriate approach.
|
||||
Maurice Obstfeld |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Emmanuel Saez |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Larry Samuelson |
Yale | Bio/Vote History | ||
The brunt of the pandemic has fallen on those at the bottom of the scale, and relief is most needed and will be most effective there.
|
||||
José Scheinkman |
Columbia University | Did Not Answer | Bio/Vote History | |
|
||||
Richard Schmalensee |
MIT | Bio/Vote History | ||
High-income households are more likely to save the money.
|
||||
Carl Shapiro |
Berkeley | Bio/Vote History | ||
This seems very clear, but there is nothing magic about using $75,000 as the upper limit.
|
||||
Robert Shimer |
University of Chicago | Bio/Vote History | ||
Wealthier households have been building up their savings and would likely do the same with any new "stimulus" checks
|
||||
James Stock |
Harvard | Bio/Vote History | ||
Higher MPC especially those liquidity constrained.
|
||||
Richard Thaler |
Chicago Booth | Bio/Vote History | ||
|
||||
Christopher Udry |
Northwestern | Bio/Vote History | ||
|